How One Jew at the Kosel Stopped an Intermarriage

He Promised, by Reb Gutman Locks

He was on a Birthright trip. When I told him he had to marry a Jewish girl he told me that he was dating a non-Jewish girl whom he liked very much.

“We can’t go by what we like. Yes, we have to like the girl we marry, but that’s not enough. Our heads have to rule over our hearts.”

I showed him in the prayer he was reading that Hashem tells us not to follow our eyes and hearts for they will lead us astray. I explained how important it is for the Jewish people to survive and for his family to remain among us.

On and on I gave him reasons to marry only a Jewish girl.

After he read the Shema I had him go stand by the Kotel and pray for his family and then to ask Hashem to guide him in whom he should marry.

Some 10 minutes later he walked back and said that he was going to call up the non-Jewish girl and break off their relationship and that he would look for a Jewish girl to marry.

I said, “Make a promise to yourself that you will marry only a Jewish girl.”

I told him that Hashem had blessed him to make that decision and that he will be thankful his entire life.

“Come back next year with the girl.”

He smiled.

He said that he promised. Please G-d, he will remember.

Thank G-d, (hopefully) we saved a Jewish family from the disaster of intermarriage.

From MPaths, here.

The Prozbul Perversion

If One More Person Says “Prozbul”…

I have a vague recollection that the first time I heard the word ‘Prozbul’ was in December 1969 at the International USY Convention in Buffalo. The subject was ‘The Sabbath’ and the thrust of many of the sessions was how to bring Sabbath observance into sync with Modern Life.  Not surprisingly, high on the agenda was the Conservative legal opinion that one is allowed to drive back and forth to the synagogue on Shabbat, a copy of which was included in the source book. I was very much taken with the supreme confidence expressed by our discussion leader, a rabbinical student at JTS, not only that the Torah could be efficiently ‘brought up to date,’ but that ‘we’ are fully qualified to do so. When asked, whence stemmed their confidence, the answer was: Prozbul.

Neither I, nor anyone else in the room, had a clue as to what a Prozbulwas so, so our leader kindly explained that the Torah annuls loans after seven years. However, this led to wealthy people not extending loans to the poor for fear of never being repaid, so Hillel created a legal fiction that annulled the annulment, overrode the Bible and that the vehicle by which this effected is entitled called ‘Prozbul’ (Cf. M. Shevi’it 10,3). We must, the leader continued, follow the example of Hillel and use it as a precedent to legislate in order to bring Judaism into the Twentieth Century. Allowing driving on Shabbat was one, sterling example of this type of activity.[1]

Over the subsequent decades, it seems that whenever I have encountered discussion of halakhic change, Prozbul is invoked.[2] Prima facie, it makes sense. After all, according to the Mishnah, Hillel the Elder did find a mechanism to address a social ill by effectively avoiding the abrogation of debts in the sabbatical year. However, the way the prozbul is cited goes far beyond this. It seems to me that it is appealed to as some sort of magic wand, an ‘Halakhah ex machina that can justify any and all situations wherein the Torah is perceived to be out of sync with the human condition.[3] Invoking Prozbul, then, is a way of expressing the (at best) extremely problematic assertion: ‘Where there’s a rabbinic will there’s an Halakhic Way.’[4]

I find this latter usage deeply distressing. Waving any kind of flag in a discussion of ideas is extremely shallow, and its use often verges on demagogy. Perhaps that explains why prozbul is a ubiquitous trope in social media. As if the Internet had not done enough damage in dumbing down contemporary intellectual intercourse, social media engenders superficiality of brain numbing proportions. Nevertheless, in the over-heated atmosphere of Facebook and Twitter polemics, whenever someone challenges the need, appropriateness or authority to change Jewish Law…out comes ProzbulQuod erat demonstrandum. ‘Nuff Said.

This type of use of prozbul is not only distressing in its shallowness, its shallowness is itself deeply offensive. After all, discussions such as these within an Orthodox context, do not concern quotidian matters. They treat of the interpretation, and application, of what Orthodox Jews are supposed to believe is ultimately the Word of God. Discussions in that context demand the polar opposite of Internet arrogance and anger, or of social media anti-norms. They require, instead, precision of thought, meticulousness of formulation, and (above all) a deep and abiding reverence for the subject and of the broad implications of the analysis. And, while I obviously cannot do anything about the comportment of others (only of my own), I would like to revisit the prozbul as a literary and intellectual topos in order to flesh out my larger point.[5]

The origins, even the very meaning, of prozbul were long debated by scholars.[6] Today, it is accepted that the word is of Greek origin, and refers to a legal instrument presented to a court.[7] As noted above, loans are annulled at the end of the sabbatical year (Shemittat Kesafim; Deut. 15, 1-2). Inter alia, this was intended to introduce a degree of debt relief for the agricultural poor. At the turn of the first millennium, though, this situation had boomeranged. In fulfillment of a situation which the Torah had envisioned, and against which it had warned, people had begun to withhold loans on the fear that they would lose their investment upon the arrival of the sabbatical year. According to the Mishnah (Shevi’it 10, 1), this situation spurred Hillel the Elder into action: [A loan secured by] a prosbul is not cancelled [in the sabbatical year]. This was one of the things instituted by Hillel the Elder. For, he saw that people refrained from lending to one another, and there transgressing that which is written in the Torah…’[8]According to the Mishnah, Hillel ruled that debts that were presented to a court for collection were unaffected by the sabbatical year amnesty.[9]

The question is, of course, whence derived Hillel’s authority and ostensible audacity at effectively circumventing the Torah’s mandated debt amnesty? Indeed, both the Yerushalmi and the Bavli express (mild?) shock at the implication that Hillel permitted something that the Torah had explicitly forbidden.[10] The best of intentions, both imply, do not justify a gross abrogation of an explicit Biblical injunction.[11] The upshot of both Talmudic discussions (part of which are anticipated in the halakhic midrashim) is that Hillel’s actions and authority lay well within the parameters of accepted Rabbinic jurisprudence, and his authority was rooted in his standing as the head of the Sanhedrin. According to one opinion, Biblical Law allowed for the exemption of debt from the sabbatical year amnesty via its assignment to a court. Or, since the amnesty itself was only rabbinic in origin already in Second Temple times, it was fully within the purview of the rabbis to legislate an exemption (Hem amru ve-hem amru).[12]

Continue reading…

From My Obiter Dicta, here.

How the Banking Cartel Bought off the Education Cartel

Blind Men’s Bluff: FED-Defending, Gold-Hating Economists

Gary North

Dec. 3, 2011

Higher education in the United States was transformed by Rockefeller money, beginning in 1902: the General Education Board. The GEB made grants to colleges only if they hired Ph.D-holding graduates of a handful of universities, which alone granted the Ph.D. This way, the universities could indirectly take over the rest of the colleges, which were mostly church-related. The strategy worked.

Rockefeller’s academic empire included the University of Chicago, which he founded. From the turn of the 20th century, the University of Chicago’s department of economics repudiated the use of gold in monetary affairs.

Milton Friedman earned his Nobel Prize for a book researched mainly by his co-author, Anna J. Schwartz: A Monetary History of the United States (1963). Born in 1915, she still works full time. In the Wikipedia entry for her, we read:

Anna Jacobson Schwartz (born November 11, 1915) is an economist at the National Bureau of Economic Research in New York City, and according to Paul Krugman “one of the world’s greatest monetary scholars”. She is best known for her collaboration with Milton Friedman on A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960 which laid a large portion of the blame for the Great Depression at the door of the Federal Reserve. She is a past president of the Western Economic Association (1988).

The book is known in academic circles and policy-making circles only for its thesis regarding the Federal Reserve System, 1930-33. It says that the FED had not inflated enough, 1930-33. The book is never quoted by the media on any other topic, although it is a fat book. That is the only academic thing that Friedman ever wrote that was adopted by his Keynesian peers. Why? Because he came out on their side.

The academic economics profession is united on only one topic: the superiority of central banking to the gold standard.

There has never been a college textbook in economics that called the FED a government-created cartel that exists for the sake of the largest banks. This outlook shapes the thinking of the students who get certified to teach. They are literally unable intellectually to apply the economic theory in the chapter on cartels to the Federal Reserve System, despite the fact that the theory in the cartel chapter fits seamlessly onto the facts of the FED. Support of central banking is basic to the entire curriculum in modern economics.

So, the graduates have a blind spot: central banking. This means they have another blind spot: a gold coin standard. It means that they have literally never examined the theory of a monetary standard that is based solely on the enforcement of voluntary exchange, including contracts. They are literally incapable of imagining a free market for money. The methodological tools which they apply with mathematical precision — a fake precision — to every other area of life, including marriage, they are intellectually incapable of applying to money.

For decades, the Federal Reserve’s Board of Governors (government) and its 12 regional banks (privately owned) have spent tens of millions of dollars (created out of nothing) handing research jobs to academic economists. The FED has literally bought off the profession. This story was concealed for years by the FED and its bought-off defenders, but it has recently surfaced.

This strategy was first adopted by the Rockefellers. John D. Rockeffer, Jr. hired Raymond Fosdick to run the Rockefeller Foundation. After he took the running of the foundation, Fosdick continued to pay public relations pioneer Ivy Lee to help reduce criticism of the Rockefeller oil empire. Lee had been on the Rockefellers’ payroll ever since 1914. One of Lee’s suggestions was to pay academics a lot of money to write pro-Rockefeller books. This worked so well that Fosdick began spending millions to buy off academia. There is a book on this: Donald Fisher, Fundamental Development of the Social Sciences: Rockefeller Philanthropy and the United States Social Science Research Council. It was published by the University of Michigan Press in 1993.

Continue reading…

From GaryNorth, here.

Why Don’t We Eat Cloves on Pesach?

Shulchan Aruch O.C. 467:8:

והמנהג במדינות אלו שלא לאכול כרכום שקורין זפרי”ן או נעגלי”ך (מהרי”ל), מיהו אינן אוסרין תערובתן וכן נראה לי.

Mishna Berurah 467:34:

או נעגעלי”ך, מפני ששורין אותן במי שעורין קודם שמייבשין אותן [ד”מ].

This is no longer the case, yet the “Minhag” remains. Of course, we aren’t Chazal, so unless there is a reason to assume this may recur (שמא יחזור הדבר לקלקולו), this is no custom at all.

There is a huge difference between stringency based on a distant (or very distant) concern, to a custom based on what others did under different conditions.